I just returned from a conference of the ABA Business Law
society in Montreal, where I was joined by several pals (Erin Fonte, Jillian
Friedman, and Denis Rice) to present on the topic of The Emerging Cashless
Society. Movement away from paper money
(or coins) to electronic payments is a global phenomenon. While other countries may be leading the United
States in moving away from cash, the United States is not far behind.
This phenomenon is primarily a product of private
ordering. People choose to transact
business with credit cards, mobile payments, or other technologies such Pay-Pal
or Dwolla rather than using currency. ( I like to use my Android Pay feature
when I am at Whole Foods or Trader Joe’s.
In fact, when the fellow ahead of me uses cash, I cannot help wondering
if the young clerk is really thinking, “what are these green papers and why do
they convey value”?) We like the
convenience, as well as some of the additional services like fraud protection,
dispute resolution, and airline miles that we get with other payment media,
which cash cannot deliver.
Governments are also pushing in this direction. Cash presents both opportunities and problems. Problems emerge because of its anonymity and
untraceable character, which permit peer-to-peer transactions without an
intermediary. Criminal enterprises prefer the certainty and finality of a cash
exchange (i.e., the counterparty cannot stop payment on the check or effect a
charge-back when the illicit goods are defective), as well as anonymity that
cash facilitates. That anonymity also creates a possibility for
tax avoidance, even among otherwise lawful enterprises, as amounts received or
paid are known only to the parties exchanging cash. Without transmission through a network that
requires an intermediary to assist in the transaction (such as a bank or
payment processor), cash keeps some information private.
A private sphere presents a threat to government, particularly when that sphere can be populated with those hatching schemes that might threaten the wellbeing of others. But the scope of that private sphere can be very important to people who are engaged in legal activities that have nothing to do with money laundering or tax avoidance. This is a growing area of tension in our society.
Cash also plays a role in monetary policy that can become an
important means of government finance. By printing paper money and using it to
buy other assets (such as debt), goods and services, government effectively gets
an interest free loan of potentially unlimited duration. The “federal reserve note” in your pocket
bears no interest and has no maturity date.
This feature of money, known as seigniorage, amounts to billions of
dollars each year, giving that more than $1 trillion of currency is in
circulation. Although electronic forms
of money could also deliver this benefit, some economists have opined that in a
cashless society, the money supply likely shrinks as there would be less demand
for paper money to be stashed away.
Government may also impose an implicit tax in the form of inflation, which affects all who hold cash, whether in paper form or
in demand deposits. That large stash of
cash that Walter White buried in the desert in Breaking Bad loses value over
time. Unlike a demand deposit, which can be readily transferred or reinvested
in other accounts or assets with a compensating interest rate, it can be harder
to invest that stash of cash, particularly if you have problems with money
laundering rules like Mr. White did.
But restricted investment opportunities also affect the
poor, who may also lack access to banking services (or face high transaction
costs) and must hold and conduct their transactions in cash. The amounts of cash they have are often not
sufficient to participate in investments that might compensate for inflation
risk. Moreover, the cash payments that they expect from wages, pensions, or government
benefits are also subject to the erosion, as these amounts adjust only
periodically, while the corrosive effect
of inflation is continuous. (Of course,
this affects all wage earners, not just the poor.)
Although debtors may benefit from inflation if the interest rate is
lower than the inflation rate, the poor who have debt are often put into high
risk pools with higher interest rates. In
contrast, note that this week, the WSJ reported that some government debt is
actually delivering a negative real interest rate due to the fact that the
nominal interest rate is actually less than some measures of inflation. Government
may benefit from this policy, but the common man may not (unless he, too, has long-term
debt at favorable rates).
Private charities, including the Gates Foundation, have been
active in working on improved financial services for the poor. But these services are the product of
innovations in payment processing, credit, and risk assessment, which are
generally driven by a motivation for profit.
The ability to make payments electronically with lower transaction costs
than cash and the ability to access lower-cost forms of credit will improve
their wellbeing. Innovations driven by
the incentive for profit offer the possibility of benefitting the common man in
significant ways. But beware of
government efforts to stoke the fires of inflation, which can undo these
positive effects.
EAM
No comments:
Post a Comment